Augar missed the chance to put English universities’ WP spending to better use

Means-tested fees discounts would remove the rationale for fruitless widening participation efforts, argues Norman Gowar

June 29, 2019
Pile of British currency notes (pounds)

As someone long retired from leading a UK university, I have watched with dismay the effects of the government’s attempts at marketisation of our sector. Sadly, these had scant attention in the recent Augar review, but I do welcome the recognition that there has been a failure to achieve effective widening participation.

Augar is right that means-tested grants should be restored because they are the most effective way of encouraging students from lower-income backgrounds to go to university. But his proposals are far too modest. This is possibly because he does not want universities to have a diminished income, yet some rough-and-ready calculations show that much more could be done even without additional government funding.

Universities already devote £800 per student on efforts to achieve widening participation, according to Augar. University submissions to the Office for Fair Access (now subsumed into the Office for Students) put the figure at £1,000. That money would not need to be spent if a more effective, means-tested grant system were put in place.

Suppose, with Augar, that tuition fees are reduced from the current level of £9,250 to £7,500 – a reduction of £1,750. Let’s see what would happen if, in addition, 10 per cent of students got a means-tested 50 per cent discount, and a further 10 per cent got a 25 per cent discount. This would be a pretty generous scheme.

A simple calculation shows that the total cost of the discounts, for fees and maintenance, would be £1,125 per student per year, spread across all students. This figure is not a million miles away from the £1,000 per student widening participation spending reported to Offa: spending that would be rendered superfluous.

Assuming that the Treasury bore the cost of the discount, that would reduce universities’ remaining shortfall to £750 per student – about 8 per cent of the £9,250 fee. If fee income from home and other European Union students is about half the total university income (widely variable but take that as an example), this would amount to a 4 per cent drop in university income. A reasonably well-managed university could easily cope with this. There is considerable fat in administrative costs – in particular, in the high number and salaries of senior managers.

But is it fair that the Treasury should pay for the discounts? I believe that it is. I do not agree with Augar that other students, of middle incomes, should be made to pay by lowering the threshold for repayments or increasing the repayment period. It can be funded from the public purse largely within current expenditures.

Lowering fees automatically generates net revenue under the accounting rules recently dictated by the Office for National Statistics. At the moment, roughly 50 per cent of student debt (Augar uses the figure of 45 per cent) is expected never to be repaid. Cutting fees by £1,750 means, therefore, that the saving to the Treasury in unpaid debt is at least £875 per student.

In addition, students from lower incomes getting the grants are likely – based on empirical studies – to have relatively low incomes as graduates. This means that under the current rules, they repay less than average. So eliminating their debt from the equation raises the savings to the Treasury even more.

Some modification of the contingent-repayment scheme could help further. Examples include changing the salary threshold for repayment (currently £25,725), the rate of repayment (currently 9 per cent of income) or the upper cap on loan repayments (currently the loan plus interest accrued) and reducing the interest rate to the retail price index.

Moreover, if the least well-off entrants were protected by means-tested grants, some of the insurance in the contingent-repayment loan scheme could be lessened. Indeed, one could move to a mortgage-type repayment system or a graduate tax. Under the former, it can be calculated that over 30 years a student with a 50 per cent means-tested grant will be repaying only £25 a month on their remaining fees, and a student with no grant is still paying only £50 a month (multiplied by two if the full maintenance loan is taken).

Such a straightforward scheme would be likely to reduce the long-term unpaid debt to minimal amounts, arising only from eventualities such as serious illness or disappearance overseas. And means-testing would be cost-neutral to the public purse.

The whole contingent-repayment scheme uses a sledgehammer to crack a nut, and it is a pity that Augar did not see fit to question it.

Norman Gowar is the former principal of Royal Holloway, University of London. He is co-author of English Universities in Crisis: Markets without Competition (Bristol University Press).

Register to continue

Why register?

  • Registration is free and only takes a moment
  • Once registered, you can read 3 articles a month
  • Sign up for our newsletter
Register
Please Login or Register to read this article.

Related articles

Sponsored